Policy Research in Macroeconomics

The IFS: viewing the economy through wrong end of a telescope

“Government debt should not be measured in pounds; it should be measured in GDPs. When GDP is high, so are tax revenues, and so is the ability of the government to repay.” 

Prof. Roger Farmer, NIESR, November, 2016 Three Facts about Debt and Deficits 

Today the Institute for Fiscal Studies produced a review of political manifestos prepared for General Election 2017. Predictably, the respected, and largely independent IFS researchers review the tax and spending proposals of the different parties with little regard for the wider economy. This skews their perspective, and their approach to analysing the economy. It is as if IFS staff consistently peer at the British economy through the wrong end of a telescope, distorting their analysis.  In other words, they view the government’s budget in much the same way as a household might assess the impact of income and expenditure on a family’s budget.

This is plain wrong. Any assessment of a party’s taxation and spending policies cannot be based on the ‘household fallacy’ – that government budgets are like household budgets and must balance. Instead tax and spending plans must be analysed in the context of Britain’s wider, but still very sluggish economy. While a household may or may not be affected by the wider economy when its members try to balance income and expenditure, a government budget is always directly affected by the wider economy. If I can be forgiven for adding to, and mixing metaphors, it is possible to think of budget deficits in terms of a see-saw. The deficit rises when the economy is weak, and falls when the economy is at full, skilled, productive and well-paid employment. 

Ten years after the implosion of the private financial system Britain has still not fully recovered from the crisis. This is not remarkable. It’s a direct consequence of both the crisis, and of Treasury policy decision-making from 2010 onwards. Today, even while the economy appears to be moving towards full employment, nominal wage growth has slowed. Inflation has risen which means that real wage growth rates are negative. In other words, inflation is stealthily cutting real wages. Falls in real wages impact negatively on the private retail, construction and other sectors of the economy.

To compound this prolonged weakness in private incomes, rates of private investment are at dismally low levels, leading to low levels of productivity.  In international league tables, Britain’s levels of investment are at rock-bottom as a share of the economic cake.  I would reproduce the World Bank’s international league table on where Britain stands in terms of investment as a percentage of GDP, if it were a) not so far down the list – 124th of 151 countries – and b) if it were not so embarrassing. These low levels of investment can partly be blamed on Britain’s dysfunctional banking and financial system.

Low levels of investment, a dysfunctional banking system, falling real incomes, low productivity – this anaemic state was exacerbated by George Osborne’s and the Treasury’s conscious decision (from 2010 onwards) to engage in a form of blood-letting, by cutting public spending and contracting the economy further. 

This helps to explain why GDP growth at 2% per year is still below the 2.8% rate of growth that preceded the crisis. To the consternation of the Office for Budget Responsibility (whose staff also tends to view the economy ‘through the wrong end of a telescope’) GDP growth is far below the optimistic levels regularly predicted. 

This is the depressing context that must inform any IFS analysis of a political party’s spending and taxation plans – but that does not. 

Given this context, how does the Labour manifesto stand up to scrutiny? Very well, I would argue, because Labour clearly recognises that the economy is still in a dire state, and understands that because of our broken banking system, the private sector is not able to invest in skilled, well-paid employment that would revive wider private sector activity, income and productivity. Given private sector weakness Labour is right to insist that any democratic government accountable to an angry electorate must step in to revive a structurally weak, and still deteriorating, private economy. 

By investing and spending into the economy, the government will generate income – for construction workers and companies building e.g. new railway lines, hospitals and wind farms; or for doctors, carers or policemen. Those incomes will be taxed – and revenues returned to the government with which to pay for the investment. Then, thanks to the multiplier, those with incomes will spend into the private sector. That in turn will generate income, including profits, for the private sector, but also  government revenues from e.g. VAT and corporation taxes. In other words, investment in construction workers, doctors and carers will ultimately pay for itself – thanks to the multiplier. 

Now I doubt the IFS applies the multiplier in its calculations and analyses, which is why it is so downbeat about the outcomes of spending.  (We know for certain that OBR does not – despite international organisations such as the IMF now acknowledging the importance of the multiplier.) 

That omission might explain why IFS staff are so concerned about ‘the cost’ of raising the minimum wage. There is not only a cost to the minimum wage – there is also the benefit of the income (both private income and tax revenues) generated and the application of the multiplier when that wage is spent – invariably in the private sector. If WH Smith e.g. were to pay a higher minimum wage to its workers, we know with absolute certainty that those workers would spend their new-found income into the economy in ways that would ultimately benefit the private sector, including WH Smith – but also the government. 

We have learnt to our cost that the multiplier works in reverse. As George Osborne and the Treasury tried hard to slash public spending – especially on the poor – the multiplier went negative.  In other words, the contractionary effects of ‘fiscal consolidation’ or ‘cuts’ had a ripple effect. The negative effects were greater than the actual cut in spending itself. 

As the National Institute of Economic Research explained in their Report on The Economic Landscape of the UK

“……..public sector spending cuts had an impact on aggregate demand which checked the expansion of the private sector but also ..reduced export demand. The result was a replacement of the lost public sector jobs by new private sector jobs but no job creation over and above this level, with the economy remaining at the initial depressed state”. 

Only when the Institute of Fiscal Studies turns the economic ‘telescope’ around – and views political parties’ plans in the context of the wider “depressed” economic landscape are we, the voting public, likely to get a more rigorous analysis of the likely impact of a political party’s plans. 

3 Responses

  1. We need to acknowledge that there are NO financial restrictions on a Government that has its own currency and is not on a gold standard or pegged to another currency.

    The only limits are resources and inflation.

    We need also to see that in the above circumstances, Taxation does not ‘fund’ anything and is more about managing behavioural change and redistribution as well as removing money to create extra fiscal space.

    Bonds aren’t really ‘borrowing’ either. They are ‘savings accounts at the treasury that bear interest (even negative at times!). Bonds shift money out of the banking system into the treasuries account at the Bank of England and are fundamentally a method of controlling interest rates buy altering the level of reserves.

    Japan (when I last looked) has a debt/GDP of 230% yet its bonds are still bought and the country has not collapsed. As Ann has often pointed out: it is the private debt in conjunction with a trade deficit that is the real issue and the nonsense that politicians bang on about national Debt is irrelevant.

    If you’ve got a trade deficit and private debt AND the Government is trying to lower the deficit there is only ONE place the money can come from which is the banking system. As economist Richard Wolff has pointed out, this is ‘bankers’ heaven’ because they love ‘renting out’ the currency to you as they make money hand over fist from this. They also love the housing bubble so that they can create loads of vast mortgages out of thin air and watch you sweat blood trying to pay it back at a rate that would need you to reincarnate to complete payments!

  2. What we do not hear & it would be interesting to do so – is why – why does the IFS not use multipliers? & why does it tend to view the UK economy like that of a household or corner shop? It would be nice to see this done forensically – by a well briefed barrister – who could strip away the elisions and nonsense and leave the IFS & its ilk like the emperor in the story – bare bummed.

  3. About 20 years ago my then boss, a builder and civil engineer, said we would end up short on all trades because they stopped proper apprenticeships. Just like there used to be SEN and SRN training on the job. All downhill

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This website collects cookies and analytic data. To use our website you must consent.
For more information read our Privacy Policy.